Corporate Philanthropy in the New Urban Economy:

 The Role of Business-Nonprofit Realignment
in Regime Politics
*

 

by

Leonard Nevarez

Department of Sociology

Vassar College

 

Accepted for publication in Urban Affairs Review

November 2000

 

 

INTRODUCTION

 

A good deal of scholarly research and public concern hypothesizes an inverse relation between economic restructuring and civic sentiment. In this scenario, economic restructuring heralds an era of rootless, globally oriented companies with little noneconomic attachment to the places they inhabit. Local investment in sectors like software, entertainment, and tourism is determined by structural shifts in information production and discretionary consumption, not entrepreneurial energies from Main Street. Thus, compared to the local histories and sentimental ties held by the traditional urban business community, firms in these new sectors lack an understanding of "how things are done" locally. For the nonprofits serving these communities, this civic disconnect threatens a decline in corporate philanthropy (e.g., Galaskiewicz 1985).

Urban political economy reframes this popular hypothesis by suggesting that corporate philanthropy signals more than local altruism. It aligns business actors to particular nonprofits and, where the latter speak for rival constituencies and advocate competing visions for urban politics, embodies a quiet strategy of business activism. Urban regime theory advances this claim by positing that corporate philanthropy not only reflects a political agenda but also helps businesses execute it. In urban regimes, coalitions of public and private actors promote various political agendas in a context of political economic structure and local agency (Elkin 1987). In the United States, for example, land-use home rule and economic competition for capital investment structurally compel local business actors to compete for and promote urban growth, but this or any other business agenda becomes policy only through negotiations with local public officials. To be stable and therefore effective, urban regimes require capacities for civic cooperation, such as selective incentives for coalition unity, shared understandings and identities, and a business structure that makes private actors amenable to cooperation. Not all regime actors are equal, however; by controlling resources like money and access to public and private decision-makers, the urban business community tends to set the informal rules for civic cooperation, even when it loses policy battles (Stone 1993, 1989). By making these capacities particularly visible, the issue of "corporate philanthropy as usual?" sheds light on how corporate activity and alliances sustain or alter the urban business community's traditional hegemony in urban regimes.

In this paper, I investigate corporate philanthropy's political consequences while heeding recent calls (e.g., Cochrane 1999; Lauria 1999) to refocus on nonlocal forces in urban politics like economic restructuring. In cities of capital disinvestment, for example, even the most savvy progressive regimes can do little to forestall the desperate quest for tax revenues and other economic resources that give "probusiness" actors and agendas the upper hand (e.g., Stites 1997; Swanstrom 1985). Are progressive possibilities more likely in the places where capital is investing? As economic restructuring in the US increases growth in postindustrial sectors, new firms move next to and in some cases crowd out the traditional urban business community, that is, Main Street mainstays from sectors like development, finance, utilities, retail, and business services. This setting provides an opportunity to investigate whether firms with new relations to localities and new ways of doing business alter the traditional business-nonprofit alignments that maintain most urban regimes. I look at local philanthropy in three diverse sectors emblematic of the new urban economy. The first, software, is shorthand for industries like software publishing, Internet services, and computer architecture design. The second, entertainment, refers to industries that produce cultural commodities and services for popular consumption, like motion pictures, recorded music, and video games. The third, tourism, includes place-based services like lodgings, restaurants, and special visitor destinations; the sector is sometimes called "hospitality," since local residents and businesses also consume these services.

I premise my inquiry around a broader theory of three domains for regime alignment&endash;three "legs" that, when properly fixed, stabilize a public-private regime of governance.1 The first is the political domain, which entails direct relations between the business community and elected/appointed officials. These can assume explicitly political forms, for example, in the electoral coalitions that support candidates and parties, or in the governmental bureaucracies that implement local policies (e.g., Ferman 1996; Whelan, Young, and Lauria 1994). Alternately, business and political leaders may work together in private-public partnerships, such as local economic development organizations, that give business actors more autonomy and less political accountability than electoral and governmental entities (e.g., Squires 1989). In classifying various configurations and levels of accountability, regime researchers have dwelled substantially on the political domain, in part because it ultimately generates the policies that constitutes "hard evidence" for regime research. In this paper, by contrast, I focus instead on the capacities for civic cooperation made possible in the second and third domains of regime alignment.

The second is the civic domain, which entails relations between community organizations, the business community, and political actors (Ferman 1996). Some civic groups are blatantly political, such as grassroots advocacy groups that oppose business community objectives or call for urban policy that does not serve a business interest. More often, organizations in the formal nonprofit sector depict themselves as "nonpolitical" and refrain from political endorsements in order to maintain tax-exempt status. Nevertheless, community nonprofits help the traditional urban business community promote its political agenda in at least three ways. First, their boards of directors provide networking and deal-making opportunities that complement other intercorporate interlocks, such as corporate directorates, business organizations, and policy discussion groups (Domhoff 1998; Useem 1984). Communication flows, local understandings are shared, and norms diffuse through these informal networks (see, e.g., Galaskiewicz 1985; Perucci and Pilsuk 1970). Second, business leaders socially construct a local "we feeling" by offering financial gifts, personal service by corporate executives and workers, and more episodic forms of business collaboration with nonprofits (Molotch 1976, 314; see also Cox 1999). Philanthropy thereby imbues corporate donors and their political agendas with nonprofits' "harmonious" social service mission (Hendon and Shaw 1987; Tesh 1984); it can favorably influence third parties like residents and decision-makers (Burt 1983), that is, when nonprofits do not advocate the local business agenda outright (see Sbragia 1990; Whitt 1987). Third, philanthropy allows business to influence the political climate by shaping the agenda of resource-dependent nonprofits (Silver 1998; Jenkins 1998; Haines 1984; DiMaggio 1983) and neglecting controversial groups and causes that criticize business activities (Wright 1985; Powell and Friedkin 1983; Pertschuk 1982). Over time, the reiteration of these functions produce a stable alignment of certain sectors for certain causes. In the local arena, for example, the traditional urban business community tends to favor a regular set of nonprofit fields and organizations, usually health and human service charities and art museums (Himmelstein 1997; Ziner 1997; Whitt and Lammers 1991; Useem 1987; Galaskiewicz 1985). The civic domain occasions my first research question: Do new urban economy firms sustain business unity by supporting the traditional urban business community's favored community nonprofits or, by contrast, align themselves to a different set of community nonprofits?2

The third domain of regime alignment is the business domain, or the interrelations of firms and business leaders involved or implicated in regime governance. Urban researchers have often overlooked this domain by assuming that businesses big and small have common interests in local growth, either for their own business or for the local market they serve (Logan and Molotch 1987). Although the evidence for businesses' common growth interests (usually dividing only over how and where to channel growth) is robust, regime theory contends that the unity of these interests must be produced through shared practices, interorganizational networks, and common understandings about the nature of community politics (Stone 1989, 175; see also Orr and Stoker 1994). Firms' amenability to these imperatives is in turn shaped by economic dynamics, corporate logics, and environmental conditions both within and without the locality. I conceptualize this amenability as business structure, which highlights what relationships and activities they participate in to carry out business and what firms need from the localities they inhabit. Typically, the business structure most conductive to uniting firms around a growth agenda involves direct and indirect reliance on local populations, businesses, land values, and other local relations whose growth translates into profits&endash;traits that Cox and Mair (1988; see also Friedland and Palmer 1984, 402) have conceptualized as local dependence.

Business structure also pertains to philanthropy, as implied in the truism that "corporate philanthropy is an oxymoron." Companies give charitably because it affects their bottom line somehow. For example, a business structure characterized by local dependence encourages a firm to target its generosity in the community, where it can best influence important third parties. Alternately, dependence on nonlocal customers, suppliers, decision-makers, and so on encourages a firm to direct its generosity toward nonprofits with national or larger constituencies (Himmelstein 1997). The business domain occasions my second research questions: Do new urban economy firms' business structures give them a different "bottom line" interest in corporate philanthropy than the traditional urban business community?

 

 

NOTES

 

* I thank the following for valuable comments on prior drafts: Harvey Molotch, Krista Paulsen, Thomas Beamish, Britta Wheeler, Todd Hechtman, Lisa Torres, and the UAR referees. This research was supported in part by U.S. Dept. of Interior, Minerals Management Service, under contract 14-35-0001-30796. Back to text.

1. I use "domains" here simply for heuristic purposes, not to supplant classificatory schemes for regime structures that already exist, such as axes (public/private growth alliances, electoral politics, bureaucratic politics: Elkin 1987) or arenas (electoral, civic, intergovernmental, etc.: Ferman 1996). Back to text.

2. This question evokes recent concerns in voluntary sector theory, which suggests that the ways in which "voluntary organizations, the state, and the corporate sector relate with one another is, and should be, historically and perhaps locally specific and embedded in socio-political-econmic-cultural context and ongoing dynamics of change" (Ostrander 1987, 128, quoted in Whitt and Lammers 1991, 388; emphasis in original). Back to text.

 

 

TO NEXT SECTION

TO TABLE OF CONTENTS